Skip to main content

Re-discussion on the rationality of high income of monopoly industries: evidence from the employer-employee matched data

Abstract

Background

Industrial income differential is the most important cause of the public dissatisfaction with the income inequality in China. The high income of monopoly industries is now the typical one of the massive income inequity phenomena. But objectively speaking, not all high income of monopoly industries is unreasonable. The income differential caused by employees’ education level is reasonable in a certain range. Measuring and analyzing the high income of monopoly industries should be based on taking various elements such as employees’ education level and working age into account.

Methods

Using the employer-employee matched data, we overcome the problem of missing variables and make the estimates of unreasonable parts of the high income of monopoly industries more reliable. By the decomposition method, the wage gaps between monopoly and competitive industries are decomposed into the reasonable part and the unreasonable part.

Results

On the average level, nearly half of the average wage difference between monopoly and competition industry is unreasonable, which is caused by monopolization. From the view of income levels, the income gaps between monopoly industry and competitive industry get widened as the income quantile increases. Specifically, at the quantile points of 10, 50, and 90%, the income gaps are 9.4, 52, and 60.6% respectively and the proportions of the unreasonable part are 26, 71, and 72% respectively.

Conclusions

The gap between the monopoly industries and competition industries is robust facts. The different decomposition method gives a consistent picture that the monopoly is the important source of the income gap. The most import source of income difference comes from the structural difference of return between the monopoly industries and competition industries.

The introduction

Income inequality, one of the major social problems in today’s China, is the object of public concern and anxiety. According to the figures released by the national bureau of statistics, our country’s residents’ income gap, measured by the Gini coefficient, has begun to fall since 2008 when it peaked after the reform and opening up. By 2014, the gap problem has been alleviated for 6 years in a row. However, public concerns and dissatisfaction about China’s income inequality have not been lessened as a result.Footnote 1 After careful inspection, observation, and consideration into the causes, we can find that the public’s dissatisfaction with the current income inequality problem in our country stems mainly from income unfairness instead of the income gap. In current China, the phenomenon of income inequality can be seen everywhere. What is worse, at present, China’s income inequality phenomenon is mostly associated with the government. Some of them are even the direct result of government policy. Official corruption, unfair high income in monopoly industries, unfair opportunities for employment, unequal administration in enjoying public service between urban and rural residents, preferential policies for more investment into and school entrance for metropolitan education and regressive taxation system are illustrations of injustice all related to the government and the government policy. These factors, without being regulated, while enlarging the income gap, will damage the fair value orientation of the whole society, and even threaten social stability. This suggests that the key to solve the income inequality problem at present in our country lies first in solving the problem of income unfairness and second in narrowing the income gap. In the future, with the increase of governmental input into social security and the rise of unskilled workers’ wages, the income gap of those residents in our country are most likely to be narrowed, but if income unfairness phenomenon is not to be corrected obviously, public concerns and dissatisfaction about income inequality will not disappear automatically.

High-income monopoly industries are currently one of the primary embodiments of income unfairness. Considering such factors as ruling foundation, national security, and national economy, such industries as oil, railways, electric power, telecommunications, and banks are endowed by CPC (China Communist Party) and the government the monopoly power, while private capital is restricted and prohibited into related fields. CPC and the government establish by themselves or allow monopoly enterprises to set up high prices for products and services provided by them. By doing so, huge economic benefits are transferred from consumers. The interests of monopoly industries, at the expense of increased consumer prices, are mainly turned into high profits in monopoly industries, high income, and welfare of practitioners and high on-the-job consumption of top executives in monopoly industries. In addition to this, it can be seen from many corruption cases in recent years that the monopoly by state-owned enterprises is an important channel to transport interests to authorities and officials, thus is an important foundation of official corruption.

The high income of monopoly industries comes from the managerial authority of monopoly enterprises endowed by the government instead of the result of enterprises’ winning in market competition. It exists at the cost of consumers’ increased expenditure and decreased welfare, thus is obviously unjustified. At this point, the public reach consensus. But, is all the high income of those practitioners in monopoly industries unreasonable? In other words, what is the proportion of the reasonable part of their high income? First, this thesis will explain why such questions are raised. From a certain sense, if we simply think all the high income of monopoly industries is unreasonable, it must be wrong. According to the calculation of the 1% sample data in 2005, the average years of education of financial industry (one of the monopoly industries) is 13.5 years, while this figure for the competition industries of manufacture and resident service is 9.6 years. The nearly 4-year gap between the two means that it is reasonable to have a salary gap between the two industries in a certain range. In addition, the salary gap caused by the factor of work experience should also be seen as reasonable. It is also unreasonable to neglect these factors and think all the income of monopoly industries as unreasonable. Such thinking, if exists, is neither objective nor helpful for the solution of problems. The right approach is, on the basis of full consideration given into reasonable factors like education and work experience for the salary gap, observation, and measurement are conducted for the proportion of unreasonable high income in monopoly industries. This is the very purpose of this thesis.

It is beneficial to divide the high income of monopoly industries into two parts—reasonable and unreasonable for a correct comprehension of the public on the high income of monopoly industries. Moreover, such research is obviously also of some significance for making policies. In document named “Decision” concerning the third plenary session of the 18th Central Committee of CPC, the issue of salary of some principals of state-owned enterprises has been specially mentioned and stipulated as follows: “state-owned enterprises should add the proportion of market-oriented recruitment, identify appropriately and strictly regulate the state-owned enterprises’ managerial personnels’ salary, administration and consumption for corresponding post and business consumption”. Then, the political bureau of the CPC central committee passed The Reform Bill of Central Administered SOE Administrators’ Salary System which includes special stipulations and limits for the salary of the administrators of the enterprises regulated the Central Committee and ministries. This also renders as reference for other related state-owned enterprises that will formulate relevant schemes aiming for reasonable salary distribution, increase, and adjustment stable for SOEs. With the comprehensive deepening of reform towards marketization, many industries have free entry and exit. However, central government-owned enterprises and other state-owned enterprises, bearing important responsibility in the development of national economy, have all sorts of administrative and economic restrictions, causing a large part of the income gap to be derived from the industry monopoly. Therefore, researching into the role of monopoly in affecting the income gap, especially the gap against high income, will allow us to know clearly about the source factors for income gap and to make proper policies.

So far, studies related to high-income issues in monopoly industries have been universal and numerous, so the literature review of here merely confine to the measurement and analysis on the rationality of the high income of monopoly industries. Judging from the data sources, research so far is divided into two categories: studies using household data and analysis using the data from enterprises. The former can be represented by researches conducted by Yue (2010), Du (2011)Footnote 2 and Yue and Cai (2015), while the latter can be illustrated by Yu and Zhang (2013a) and Yu and Zhang (2013b). In terms of research methods, apart from Yue and Cai (2015), there is no exception for all the other researches to focus on the rationality of the average salary gap between monopoly and competition industries by employing Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition method. Different from the above method, Yue and Cai (2015) use the Machado-Mata decomposition method based on the regression of multiple quantiles to measure the proportion of reasonable and unreasonable salary gap between monopoly industries and competitive industries. On the estimated results, apart from some individual documents, these studies are consistent in research results—most of the high income of monopoly industries’ practitioners is unreasonable and exists due to monopoly. For example, according to the estimates made by Yue (2010), the vast majority of decomposition results show that more than 70% of the high income in monopoly industries is unreasonable. Two studies using enterprises’ data also draw roughly the same conclusions. In addition, analysis results of the studies conducted by Yue and Cai (2015) demonstrate that the proportion of the unreasonable part of high income is positively proportionate to the income level. This means the higher the practitioners’ income is, the higher the proportion of unreasonable income of the monopoly industries is.

Previous researches do have certain defects like a limited range of data. As mentioned above, previous studies either use data from the household survey, or from business surveys, with the former including only the practitioners’ information of individual attributes and the latter containing only the information at enterprise levels. In other words, income analysis using household survey will be unable to review the influence of their enterprises on their income. On the contrary, those employing surveys conducted by enterprises will not be able to consider the effect of such factors of individual attributes as gender, age, and education on their income. Different from previous research, this paper use enterprise-employee matching data, namely, a kind of data including both information on individuals and the enterprises employees are working in. Thus, it has significant advantages and is more reliable. In addition to the advantage of the data, this article will also inspect and analyze the share taken by the unreasonable part of the high income of monopoly industries’ practitioners from the perspective of average value and income distribution (i.e., quantile decomposition). Decomposition results of this paper can be summarized as follows: at the average levels, with the increase of quantiles, the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries is gradually increasing: when quantiles are at the levels of 10, 50, and 90%, the monopoly industries’ incomes are 9.4, 52, and 9.4% higher than those of the competition industries respectively. The proportion of the unreasonable part of the income gap also rises with the rise of quantiles. More specifically, the proportions of unreasonable part are 26, 71, and 26% respectively. This conclusion is consistent with previous studies basically. In other words, the conclusion that high income of monopoly industries is basically unreasonable is undoubtable.

The research methods

The purpose of this study is to analyze the contribution by industrial monopoly to the salary gap. In the literatures, the research about the salary gap is comparatively mature, which can be seen from decomposition based on the average (Oaxaca and Ransom 1994; Blinder, 1973; Cotton, 1988; Neumark, 1988) to the decomposition of the income distribution (Machado and Mata, 2005; Firpo et al. 2009), showing that each decomposition method gives a new perspective for research questions.

When measuring unreasonable part in the high income of monopoly industries, Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition is a method widely applied. Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition is based on regression analysis, which means the salary of each industry is jointly determined by both individual characteristics and the returns of characteristics. Different industries have different individual characteristic distribution and return coefficients, thus we can use the differentials on different industries’ characteristic distribution and the return coefficients, and decompose their income differentials. The salary determination equation estimated by this paper not only controls the characteristics of individual human capital but also controls the operating characteristics of the enterprises as employers. According to human capital theory, individuals’ income is severely affected by one’s education age, position, and professional skills, but the wages of workers are also closely related with the enterprises’ operating conditions. This paper uses enterprise-employee matching data, making this paper able to estimate the individual salary income and control the characteristics of the enterprise at the same time, which solves the problem of missing variables. Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition can identify salary determination mechanism for different industries, compare the differentials between sources of the average salary of different industries, and determine the unreasonable part of income of the monopoly industries compared with competition industries. In constructing counterfactual distribution, the rate of returns of competition industries is usually used as a standard. The characteristics of the monopoly industries’ individuals and the rate of returns of competitive industries are used to calculate the proportion of the reasonable income for not being in monopoly industries. For constructing counterfactual distribution of the income of individuals working in monopoly industries, there are also other structures, thus in decomposing the contribution of salary gap by different factors, there are other decomposition methods. For instance, when calculating the contribution by individual attributes, monopoly industries’ returns can be used; while calculating the contribution of the rate of return, the average of individual attributes in competition industries is used. Such decomposition is called inverse decomposition, using the rate of returns in monopoly industries as a reasonable rate of return for individual characteristics in composing counterfactual distribution. Using these two kinds of decomposition methods, reasonable and unreasonable parts of the income gap are usually not completely the same. As to which one is more accurate to estimate real reasonable and unreasonable parts of the income gap, the answer lies in the estimated returns of which one in the two groups is closer to that of the competitive labor market. For the two groups of monopoly industries and competitive industries in this paper, the labor market in competition industries is likely to be closer to that of the competitive labor market, so the decomposition based on rate of returns of competitive industries may be more ideal. But when explaining decomposition results, in order to verify the stability of the decomposition results, the paper presents the decomposition results of two kinds of decomposition methods at the same time. As there is attribute variables in explanatory variables, there will be a problem of selecting which one group of dummy variables as a reference group. Selecting different reference groups will produce tremendous differential in decomposition methods, which is called index issue. As to index issue, there have been many explorations and studies in literature, of which Cotton (1988) and Oaxaca and Ransom (1994) is the most typical one. This paper also presents the decompositions made by Cotton and Oaxaca and Ransom. In estimating the unreasonable part of the high income in monopoly industries, the results produced with various methods are basically identical.

Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition focuses on the source of the differentials of the average income distribution, but there may be great differential in density and distribution of the income distribution of monopoly industries and competition industries at different levels. If consideration is given to monopoly industries’ practitioners’ characteristics and the differential of their income when according to the elemental rate of returns in competition industries, we need to take the affecting factors at different levels in counterfactual distribution into account. DFL decomposition methods have already noticed the differential of income distribution at different locations, but it has not directly taken the differential of elemental rate of returns of income distribution at different locations into consideration (DiNardo J, Fortin NM, Lemieux T, 1996). Moreover, DFL decomposition methods need to estimate the weighting function. If there are errors between estimated equation and real equations, the explanation for the results will also be affected.

The approach used by Machado and Mata (2005) and Melly (2005) is to estimate the distribution of counterfactual income on the basis of conditional quantiles. However, the elemental rate of returns for estimating the equations of conditional quantiles can only affect conditional quantiles. The differentials among conditional quantiles belong to those on income distribution with certain characteristics, while differentials among unconditional quantiles are the reflections of those among real income distribution. The quantiles of real income are not only affected by equations of conditional quantiles, thus the size of rate of returns is not a direct function of conditional variables. Quantiles are nonlinear functions comparing corresponding variables of characteristics with income distribution. Unconditional quantiles need to be estimated by integrals. Firpo (2009) uses the concepts of recentered influence function (RIF decomposition) in statistics to develop a decomposition method based on the regression of unconditional quantiles. This method enlarges the decomposition method of Oaxaca-Blinder, making decomposition of the differential on the unconditional distribution of income distribution possible. The core of decomposition is to estimate the income’s role in determining the characteristics of equations and rate of returns and to use the rate of returns in competition industries as well as the characteristics of monopoly industries to estimate the counterfactual income of monopoly industries, dividing the differentials of the income distribution in monopoly industries into two parts—reasonable characteristics’ effects and unreasonable structural effects.

This thesis uses such methods comprehensively, inspecting the salary differential between monopoly industries and competition industries and its source and analyzing the contribution of different rates of returns caused by monopoly in income inequality.Footnote 3

Data description

This article uses the enterprise-employee matching data in 2009 collected and sorted by the Research Institute of China’s income distribution, Beijing Normal University. As to the definition of monopoly industries, we took the methods adopted by Yue (2010) for reference, using a two-digit industry code to divide monopoly industries and competition industries, with the former including 10 industries—oil and gas, tobacco manufacturing, oil processing and coking and nuclear fuel processing, railway transportation, water transport, air transport, postal services, telecommunications and other information transmission services as well as the financial industry and the latter containing 14 categories including the wholesale and retail groups, construction groups, as well as manufacturing. All the 14 kinds of manufacturing parts belong to light industry. Metals, equipment manufacturing, machinery in the manufacturing sector in Yue, etc. (2010) were not included in the competition industry but listed as in other sectors. This is because these industries include the military enterprises that cannot be distinguished from military industry enterprises. Data in this paper do not include that of military enterprises. Wang and Whalley (2014) calculated the concentration index of Chinese manufacturing companies and compared the manufacturing concentration of manufacturing in China and the USA. They found in their calculations that the concentration of Chinese manufacturing industry between 2002 and 2007 was less than that of the US companies, so it is rational to classify the metals, equipment manufacturing, and machinery sectors as competition industries.Footnote 4 Comparing the data by Yue (2010), the monopoly industries in this article do not contain oil and gas industry, and competition industries do not include accommodation catering industry and residents’ service as well as other services.

For monopoly industries we observed and gathered information about 74,274 individuals of 298 enterprises. While for competitive industry, the information comes from 198,970 employees of 1440 enterprises. The information about the distribution of enterprises and employees of both monopoly and competition industries are shown in Table 1. There is information about the characteristics of enterprises and business operation in this paper. We compared the performance and characteristics of monopoly industries and competitive industries in Table 2. According to the subordinate relations among enterprises, we divided them into three types: enterprises regulated by the central government or provincial government, enterprises regulated by cities and counties, and other enterprises. Monopoly enterprises belong to a relatively higher level, of which 20% belong to the central government or provincial government, while only 8% of competition industries belong to the central government or provincial government. Fifty-five percent of monopoly industries belong to cities or counties, while the figure of competition industries is 46%. So there are more enterprises that do not belong to any authority or government below county levels. According to the type of registration, the enterprises are divided into domestic-funded enterprises, enterprises funded by Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan, and foreign enterprises. This article combines enterprises funded by Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan and foreign enterprises into one group, so all the enterprises are divided into domestic and foreign enterprises. As for monopoly, domestic enterprises take up a higher proportion, for 93% of them are domestically funded. But in competition industries, there is an even higher proportion of foreign enterprises. As for the scale of enterprises, there are two types of enterprises that are above medium-scale and small enterprises. The differential on distribution between monopoly industries and competition industries from the perspective of scale is not quite huge, for 25% of the monopoly industries are those with a scale above a medium level, which is close to 26%, the figure for competition industries. The number of staff is also a frequent index to measure the scale of enterprises. It can be seen from Table 2 that the scale of enterprises in monopoly industries is larger than the number of staff for an average firm in competition industries. Viewed from the median, the number of staff for an average firm in monopoly industries is 121.5, while the figure for enterprises in competition industries is 66.

Table 1 The number and distribution of enterprises and practitioners of different industries
Table 2 Comparison of the operating characteristics of monopoly and competitive industries

Data in this thesis also include the sales, profit, and incremental of enterprises. We use the average number of employees in an enterprise to calculate the average operation index and compare the operational performance between monopoly industries and competition industries. From Table 2 we can see that there are great differentials in operation situations among enterprises in monopoly industries. Although the proportion of enterprises with loss in monopoly industries is quite high, the proportions of average profit and average incremental are higher than the corresponding index in competition industry. The profit per capita in monopoly industry is 7.8 thousand yuan, while the median of the average profit in enterprises of competition industries is 3.5 thousand yuan; the median of the average sales in monopoly industries is 336.1 thousand yuan, while the median for the average sales in monopoly industries is 326 thousand yuan. The average incremental is also a measurement on enterprises’ operation situation. The median of the average incremental in monopoly industries is 53.4 thousand yuan, while the median of average incremental in competition industries is 36.6 thousand yuan. As the incremental of financial industry is not calculated and there is lack of data about enterprises’ incremental, the number observed on average incremental is less than other indexes of enterprises.

For different positions, the forms to pay salaries are also different, thus hourly salary is a reasonable index for income. The data includes the annual income and working hours for each employee, thus we calculate the hourly pay for each employee. From Table 4 we also can see that the average hourly salary for employees in monopoly industries is 23.18 yuan, while this figure for competition industries is 17.52 yuan, with the former higher than the latter by 32.3%. Judging from income distribution, Table 3 gives us the levels of income at the levels of quantiles of 90 and 10 as well the median of the distribution of the logarithm of hourly salary. Whether at the lower part or higher part, the income of monopoly industries is higher than that of competition industries. The quantile of 10 in monopoly industries’ income is 1.81, but 1.72 in competition industries. The quantile of 90 in monopoly industries’ income is 3.68, but this figure for competition industries is 3.11. The inequality in practitioners’ income in monopoly industries is more serious than that of competition industries. The standard deviation and Gini coefficient of monopoly industries’ income are 0.62 and 0.16 respectively, while these figures for competition industries are 0.39 and 0.14 respectively.

Table 3 Distribution characteristics of logarithmic hourly wage of different industries

In this thesis, the data also include the information about individual employee’s social characteristics like gender, education, position, and professional skills. Thus we can compare the social characteristics of the employees between monopoly industries and competition industries. From Table 4 we can find the proportion of males higher than competition industries. In monopoly industries the percentage of males is 68%, while in competition industries the percentage is 52%. The practitioners in competition industries tend to be younger with an average age of 35.44, while the average age of practitioners in monopoly industries is 36.75. The academic degrees of the practitioners in monopoly industries are higher, of whom 42% own degrees above junior college and receive education for an average of 12.92 years, while in the competition industries practitioners owning degrees of or above junior college account for 25% and receive education for an average of 11.82 years. From perspectives of positions and skills, 72% of them are at the management positions or have qualifications for professional skills in monopoly industries. However, in competition industries, such figure is only 57%. The proportion of personnel attending labor union is higher than that of competition industries. Eighty-eight percent of the employees in monopoly industries are members of a labor union, while only 72% attend labor unions in competition industries. From the perspective of regional distribution, there is no big difference in the regional distribution between monopoly industries and competition industries. Both industries have 80% of their employees working in the eastern region and with only 5% working in the western region. The employment rate of employees of monopoly industries is higher than competition industries, which is consistent with the proportion in domestic enterprises in monopoly industries. For the scale of enterprises they are employed, the proportion of being employed by enterprises above a medium level is greater in competition industries. Seventy percent are employed in enterprises above a medium level in competition industries while 59% is the figure for monopoly industries.

Table 4 Statistics on the description of individuals’ social characteristics for different industries

Viewing at the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries loggers, the revenue of the former is higher than that of the latter. But the social characteristics such as education, gender, and age are different from that of competition industries, so does the operation situation of the two. Therefore, in analyzing the income gap between the two, differentials of individual human capital and the characteristics of enterprises they are working in must be considered.

Main results

Decomposition of average income

The aim of this thesis is to measure the proportion of unreasonable part of the high income of monopoly industries. Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition methods can respectively identify the system to determine salary for different industries and compare the origins of the average income gap among different industries to identify the unreasonable part of the revenue of monopoly industries against competition industries.

Table 5 demonstrates a regression model of the salary equations and estimates the equations to determine the salary of both monopoly industries and competition industries. As a comparison, we compare the features of the enterprises that the controlled employees are working in and the estimates of the social characteristics of the individual employee. It can be seen that there are differentials between the factors affecting the rate of returns between the monopoly industries and compassion industries. On the rate of returns of human capital, the income gap between female and male in monopoly industries is smaller than competition industries. In monopoly industries, the salary of male is higher than that of female by 9.3%, while in competition industries this figure is 19%. However, in the monopoly industries, the rate of returns from education is higher. For each increase of 1 year spent on education, the income for monopoly industries increases 16% and the income of competition industries increase 8.4%. The salary of monopoly industries increases with the increasing of age, which is presented with the shape of an inverted “U”, while competition industries are still in a phase where the salary increases as the age grows larger. Regardless of monopoly or competition industries, the salary of practitioners in the eastern and central regions of China is relatively higher. In competition industries, both the management position and owning professions’ certifications can bring the increase of salary, but in the monopoly industries, owning professions’ certificates and the management position do not bring obvious advantages. When the characteristics of enterprises are added, in the equation to determine the salary of monopoly industries, R-squared value increases by 15%, while the figure in competition industries is 9%. This shows that the characteristics of enterprises can truly affect the income of their employees. From the perspective of the characteristics of enterprises, no matter what kind of the enterprises they are—monopoly industries or competition industries, the salary of the unprofitable enterprises is decreasing. But the income of the practitioners in monopoly industries and competition industries is sensitive with different degrees to the scale and levels of profit of an enterprise. The sales can only measure the scale of enterprises. In competition industries, income of the practitioners working in an enterprise with a higher sale per capita is relatively higher. By comparison, in monopoly industries, the large scale of enterprises does not bring any advantage. In monopoly industries, the income of the employees in enterprises with a profitable level is also higher, but in the competition industries, where the coefficients of the rates of returns for profit is negative, meaning the income of practitioners in enterprises with a high profit is not so high. This result may be caused by the period that the data was in. In the year of 2009, affected by the financial crisis, the profit of manufacturing industries decreases, but the salary of employees did not change due to the limit of contracts, making the profit and salary per hour negatively correlated; increased labor cost may also cause profit to decrease. As the data in thesis is cross sectional, we cannot distinguish from these two explanations. But monopoly industries and competition industries perform differently under either case.

Table 5 Regression result of salary equation’s OLS

Table 6 shows the result of estimating the reasonable and unreasonable income gaps of both monopoly industries and competition industries. The average salary per hour in monopoly industries is higher than that of competition industries by 41%. Taking the coefficients of the rate of returns from the salary in competition industries, of the average salary gap between monopoly industries, and competition industries, 51.63% can be justified by the individual characteristics and business operation characteristics of both monopoly industries and competition industries, while the rest 48.37% represents the part that cannot be explained. If we take the coefficients of the rate of returns in monopoly industries as the elemental rate of returns in counterfactual distribution, the proportion taken by a reasonable part of the salary gap drops by 19.20%. In contrast, the share taken up by an unreasonable part rises to 80.80%. The differential of the two results may partly be because of the index that has been mentioned in this paper. This thesis also reports other two results for decomposition, in which the unreasonable part of the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries remains at levels of 63 and 72%. This demonstrates that even if the scale, profit status, and profit level of enterprises are controlled, there is still a salary gap between competition industries and monopoly industries and a big proportion of it cannot be explained by the differential of the practitioners’ characteristics.

Table 6 Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition of the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries

The findings of this paper are similar to that of the research by Yue (2010) who uses the data from household surveys to analyze the reasonable and unreasonable parts of the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries and finds the unjustified part of the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries contributes more than 48%. In comparison, this thesis also inspects the influence of controlling human capital on the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries. From Table 6 we can also see the changes on the proportion of the unreasonable part of the salary gap between the monopoly industries and competition industries when there is only control on human capital. But no matter what decomposition methods we use, there is no reversion on the ratio between unreasonable and reasonable parts. In the salary gap, inexplicable part still takes up a key share. Monopoly is still an important source of the salary gap between industries.

Decomposition of the salary gap by quantiles

Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition methods provide both the parts of explicable and inexplicable parts in the differential of the average value of the salary distribution. But in the whole income distribution, apart from the average income, there is differential in the income distribution at different locations. In this paper, DFL decomposition technology is used and the method of weighting is used to compose counterfactual distribution in order to compare the reasonable and unreasonable parts of the salary at different locations. The idea of DFL decomposition methods is similar to that of Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition framework and aims to decompose the salary gap into effects on characteristics and structures. Effects on characteristics are changes of income distribution that is caused by the distribution differential of those variables of characteristics determining income among different industries, while the structural effects refer to the effects caused by the differential on rate of returns on characteristics caused by different income levels from different industries, thus are the inexplicable part of the salary gap. By using the rate of returns of competitive industries, we can calculate the counterfactual distribution which is produced when characteristics distribution likens monopoly industries but income is calculated according to the rate of returns in accordance with competition industries. Figures 1 and 2 demonstrate the comparison among monopoly industries, competition industries, and counterfactual distribution.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Distribution of monopoly industries’ salary and counterfactual salary. The solid line is monopoly industry wage distribution density. The dash line is the counterfactual wage distribution density

Fig. 2
figure 2

Distribution of competition industries’ salary and counterfactual salary. The solid line is competition industry wage distribution density. The dash line is the counterfactual wage distribution density

Figure 1 shows that compared with counterfactual distribution in competition industries, the income of monopoly industries is close to that of the low income, but it has a bigger density at the part of high income, and its distribution is shifting towards the right. Figure 2 shows that when the individual characteristics of monopoly industries acquire income in accordance with the rate of returns in competition industries, counterfactual distribution is similar to that of competition industries.

Table 7 gives us the information of the decomposition of the different structure and characteristics according to different statistical features as well as their contribution proportion to the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries. Of the gap of the average value between monopoly industries and competition industries, the proportion between the explicable and inexplicable parts is similar to the result of Table 6, but the inexplicable proportion by DFL decomposition is higher. The income inequality of monopoly industries is higher than that of competition industries. We can see from Table 7 that monopoly industries are higher than competition industries from both perspectives of variance and Gini coefficients. When decomposed as gap on structure and characteristics, contribution rate of inexplicable part to the inequality exceeds 65%, meaning that the inequality among industries comes mostly from different rates of returns instead of differential on the distribution of practitioners’ characteristics and enterprises’ operation characteristics.

Table 7 Salary gap calculated by DFL weighting method

It can be seen from the differential on quantiles of income distribution in Table 7 that income of monopoly industries is higher than the income of competition industries at respective quantiles. With the improvement of income, the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries is enlarging. At 10 quantiles of the income distribution, the income of monopoly industries is higher than competition industries by 10%. At the median, the income of monopoly industries is higher than competition industries by 47%. At 90 quantiles, the income of the monopoly industries is higher than competition industries by 58%. Viewing from the source of income gap, at the place where the low income distributes, a gap caused by characteristics accounts for an important proportion of the income gap, while at the place where high-income distributes, a structural gap accounts for a key proportion. At 10 quantiles, an explicable part accounts for 37.01% of the salary gap. Thus, the differential at the lower part of income between monopoly industries and competition industries is mainly due to the differential on the individual characteristics of the practitioners and enterprises, while the differential on the higher part of the income comes largely from the differential of the mechanism to determine the elemental rate of returns from salary among industries.

Robustness test

It can be seen from Table 1 that there are great differentials on the density and distribution of the income distribution between monopoly industries and competition industries at different income levels, thus concerning only about the gap between the average values will neglect the differential and source of income distribution at different levels. DFL methods have taken the differential of income distribution at different levels into account, but excluding the differential on the elemental rate of returns for income at different places of income distribution. Machado and Mata (2005) proposed a regression model for conditional quantiles, supposing the equations to determine income at different quantiles with different income distributions between monopoly industries and competition industries. First, we should estimate equations to determine income for different quantiles in accordance with conditional quantiles’ model. Then we use the elemental rate of returns for different quantiles that have been estimated. For the features of monopoly industries’ practitioners, we can compose the counterfactual distribution under the assumption that those elemental features of monopoly industries acquire income in accordance with the elemental rate of returns from competition industries and then compare the gap between the income distribution of monopoly industries and counterfactual distribution. Finally, we can get the influence caused by the inexplicable factors of different elemental rate of returns and those explicable factors of different distributions of practitioners’ characteristics in producing the gap between monopoly industries and competition industries.

The method adopted by Machado and Mata (2005) as well as Melly (2005) is to estimate counterfactual income distribution on the basis of conditional quantiles, but the elemental rate of returns estimated by conditional quantiles is only a function of conditional quantiles. Quantiles are nonlinear functions of the variables of characteristics, thus the rate of returns is not the result of the direct influence on the quantiles of incomes distribution by corresponding variables of characteristics. The RIF decomposition method developed by Firpo, et. al (2009) on the basis of unconditional quantiles’ regression enlarges the decomposition from average value to the whole salary distribution and replaces the regression of conditional quantiles through unconditional quantiles, in order to decompose the characteristics’ gap and the structural gaps of elemental rate of returns to the variable of various characteristics.

This thesis uses two decomposition methods—conditional quantiles and unconditional quantiles—to examine the income gap at different levels of income distribution between monopoly industries and competition industries and its source. Table 8 shows the income gap estimated by the conditional quantiles’ model by Melly (2005). As the quantiles of income increase, the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries is gradually being enlarged. At the lower part of the income (10 quantiles), income of monopoly industries is only higher than that of competition industries by 10%, while at the median part, such figure is 47% and at the higher part of 90 quantiles, the number is 63%. After decomposing the gap of income between monopoly industries and competition industries into characteristics gap caused by different distribution of practitioners’ features and structural gap due to different elemental rates of returns for different industries, it can be seen that the income gap at the lower part of income mainly comes from the explicable part, while at the middle and higher parts of income, the income gap largely comes from the inexplicable part caused by elemental rates of returns. At the lower part of income (10 quantiles), the inexplicable part of the income gap takes up only 26.39%, while at the median part, such figure reaches 71.12%. At the higher part of income (90 quantiles), such number reaches 72%. These results are similar to those in Table 7 where at the higher part of high-income distribution, the inexplicable part takes an increasingly large share.

Table 8 Decomposition of conditional quantiles for the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries

Table 9 gives us the RIF decomposition results of unconditional quantiles by Firpo (2009). From the first two columns, it can be seen that the differential between the income gap estimated by RIF equations and the gap of quantiles from original data as well the gap with average value is quite small. The income gap of quantile 10 of the unconditional quantiles between monopoly industries and competition industries 0.10, while the income gap estimated by RIF decomposition methods is 0.10. At the quantile of 90 of high income, the income gap of quantiles of original data is 0.58, while that gap estimated by RIF methods is 0.58. At different levels of income distribution, we can see the source of the income gap estimated by RIF and the estimated results by conditional quantiles in Table 8 are quite similar. For 10 quantiles of low income, 149% of the income gap comes from the explicable characteristics’ gap, while at the medians of the income, the explicable part of the income gap drops to 55%. At the quantiles of 90 of the high income, the proportion of the part originating from explicable factors in the income gap drops to 36.44%. Thus, with the improvement in the income distribution, the proportion caused by the inexplicable part grows higher.

Table 9 RIF decomposition of quantiles for the salary gap between monopoly industries and competition industries

In a word, judging from the decomposition of the income gap at different income distribution levels, as the location of income distribution moves higher, the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries is increasing, so does the proportion of inexplicable part from the income gap. At the part of low income where the income of monopoly industries and competition industries distributes, the income gap is mainly caused by gaps on the characteristics of practitioners and enterprises, while at the part of high income where income distributes, the income gap is mainly produced by inexplicable factors such as elemental rates of returns.

Discussion

The gap between the monopoly industries and competition industries is robust facts. The different decomposition method gives a consistent picture that the monopoly is the important source of the income gap. The characteristics difference is partial explanation for the income gap. The most import source of income difference comes from the structural difference of return between the monopoly industries and competition industries. We confirm the finding in the literature and provide more solid support. As other researches, the paper studies the static income difference. We do not know the labor mobility in different industry. The monopoly and barrier to entry will also reduce the labor allocation among industries which therefore affect the long-term income difference.

Conclusions

Income gap between industries is one source for the differentials on income and also the result of barriers preventing labor force from flowing into the market and restricted access. As China’s labor market is growing mature, the obstacles for free allocation of labor force are becoming less gradually. With gradual realization of the reform of household registration system and the overall plan for national social security and medical system, factors limiting the flow of labor force among regions gradually decrease, making a national market for labor forces gradually take shape. However, the barriers and limitations among industries lead the factors affecting the entrance and exit of industries to become an emergent problem. Only by allocating labor forces among different industries freely can the distortions on resource allocation caused by limiting labor forces become less and less, quickening the free flow of talents and providing new motivation for China’s economic transformation and sustainable development.

This thesis analyzes the influence of industrial monopoly on income gap, that is, the average income of monopoly industries is higher than competition industries. Analysis on the gap at different income distribution levels demonstrates that the higher the income is, the larger the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries is. Using the equations for salary determination, this thesis analyzes both the explicable and inexplicable parts of the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries. We find that the inexplicable part of the income gap increases after enterprises’ characteristics and individual factors are controlled, which can be deemed as improvement and supplement for missed factors analyzing enterprises in literatures. Furthermore, using the decomposition method of quantiles’ regression, we inspect the proportion of inexplicable part in income gap at different income distribution levels. At the low income part, the explicable part takes up more shares of the income gap, while at the high income part, the proportion occupied by the explicable part decreases. Thus, industrial monopoly is more beneficial for those who earn a high income than low income earners. The index of income inequality of monopoly industries is higher than that of competition industries, implying that there is no trend of balanced income in monopoly industries.

Promoting income fairness among industries is a key component in income distribution strategy. The barriers for labor force’s flow caused by monopoly enlarge the income gap among different industries, cause income inequality, and increase the separation among people. At a certain period, there are reasonable historical factors for monopoly. Thus, administration on the income gap among industries must give full play to both the government and market. From the perspective of government, we must strengthen the transformation of governmental functions and give its role of supervision into full play. The source of high income in industrial monopoly is monopoly profits, so strengthening the supervision and regulation on monopoly industries’ profits and market behaviors would control the profit level reasonably. By strengthening checks on anti-monopoly behaviors of monopoly industries, fair operation of the market would be promoted and enterprises’ market behavior would be regulated. Rational supervision on pricing by monopoly industries would not only curb monopoly profits but also lessen the operation cost of other related enterprises in the market, add economic visor, and reduce the losses on efficiency caused by monopoly pricing. Second, we should gradually increase the proportion and improve the mechanism for the bonus of state-owned enterprises, increase governmental fiscal income, and add civil expenditure or transfer payment through the government in order to rationally use monopoly profits. From the perspective of market, with the advances on the Internet and newly emerging technologies, changes happen to industrial structures and barriers. Therefore, while reducing unnecessary administrative approval, the government should explore on the regulation on negative list and regulate industries by classifying them, remove confinement and restricted access unsuitable to economic situations, and give the market a bigger role to play in allocation resources.

Moreover, regulating monopoly industries is also one of the key elements when reforming state-owned enterprises. While building a reasonable mechanism for enterprises’ salaries, we should perfect the supervision mechanism for enterprises’ performance and strengthen the regulation and management on enterprises’ operation by external organizations. Bringing the party into full play when supervising and regulating monopoly industries would make up for the insufficient factors of motivation and coordination in the administration framework of state-owned enterprises and perfect the incentive mechanisms in supervision management and assessment as well as evaluation. Meanwhile, we should promote reforms on the state-owned enterprises for mixed ownership, give private economy proper rights for administration, gradually abandon the old outlook that state-owned shares are golden ones, and change ways of handling matters in the hope of promoting state-owned enterprises’ reform towards marketization, attracting private capital and forming new behavior subjects in market economy.

Notes

  1. Income distribution has been a hot point of grassroots’ concerns, which can be demonstrated by a survey conducted by people.com on the hot points for NPC and CPPCC in 2015 whose result shows income distribution is one of the top ten hot points. The following website can be referred: http://npc.people.com.cn/GB/28320/392528/index.html,accessed Mar 20 2016.

  2. According to Du (2011), the unreasonable part of the high income in monopoly industry is estimated to be one third, which is obviously lower than the figure from other studies. The reason for this cannot be known by a glance. In using data, Du (2011) and Yue (2010) as well as Cai (2015) are similar, that is, the subsamples all belong to the 1% of 2005 population survey. However, the research by Du used only samples from Beijing City and other researchers used national samples. In addition, on the definition for practitioners, monopoly industries and competition industries, there are some differences between researches by Du and others.

  3. Detailed introduction on various decomposition methods can be referred to Fortin, Lemieux, Firpo (2011) and Guo (2011).

  4. Metal, equipment manufacturing and machinery sections include 15 industries with two digits like chemical raw materials and chemical products’ manufacturing industry, metal and non-metal manufacturing industry and equipment manufacturing industry. Comparison under the condition of different definitions between the characteristics of enterprises in competition industry and individual characteristics shows that the results are all similar. Usage of the data analysis for an enlarged scope of competition industry shows that the analysis on the income gap between monopoly industries and competition industries will produce no substantive differences. Due to the space limit, we would not report on the analysis of result stability.

References

  • Blinder AS (1973) Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural Estimates. J Hum Resour 8(4):436–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotton J (1988) On the decomposition of wage differentials. Rev Econ Stat 70(2):236–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiNardo J, Fortin NM, Lemieux T (1996) Labor market institutions and the distribution of wages, 1973-1992: A semiparametric approach. Econometrica 64(5):1001–1044

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du X (2011) The income gap between China’s monopoly industries and competition industries: A research based on micro data in Beijing. Nankai Econ Stud (Nankai Jingji Yanjiu) 5:111–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Firpo S, Fortin NM, Lemieux T (2009) Unconditional quantile regressions. Econometrica 77(3):953–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fortin N, Lemieux T, Firpo S (2011) Decomposition methods in economics. Handbook of labor economics 4, North Holland, pp 1–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo J, Jiang L, Lu L (2011) Review on the decomposition methods of salaries’ differentials. China Econ Q (Jingjixue Jikan) 10(2):363–414

    Google Scholar 

  • Machado JA, Mata J (2005) Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regression. J Appl Econ 20(4):445–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melly B (2005) Decomposition of differentials in distribution using quantile regression. Labour Econ 12(4):577–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark D (1988) Employers’ discriminatory behaviour and the estimation of wage discrimination. J Hum Resour 23(3):279–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca RL, Ransom MR (1994) On discrimination and decomposition of wage differentials. J Econ 61(1):5–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang J, Whalley J (2014) Are Chinese markets for manufactured products more competitive than in the US? A comparison of China–US industrial concentration ratios., NBER Working Paper, No. 19898

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Yu L, Zhang J (2013a) Empirical studies into the effect of china’s monopoly industries’ income distribution. Res Financ Econ Issues (Caijing Wenti Yanjiu) 1:24–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Yu L, Zhang M (2013b) Empirical studies into monopoly and the factors influencing the industrial income gap. Res Econ Manage (Jingji Yu Guanli Yanjiu) 10:15–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Yue X, Cai M (2015) Studies into the degree of irrationality of high income in monopoly industries. China Ind Econ (Zhongguo Gongye Jingji) 5:5–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Yue X, Li S, Sicular T (2010) Explorations into the high income of monopoly industries. Soc Sci China (Zhongguo Shehui Kexue) 3:77–93

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

There is no funding for this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

HN executes all computation and calculation. The two authors contribute equally to design and writing. Both authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Haifeng Nie.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nie, H., Yue, X. Re-discussion on the rationality of high income of monopoly industries: evidence from the employer-employee matched data. China Financ. and Econ. Rev. 5, 10 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40589-017-0056-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s40589-017-0056-0

Keywords